Winners don’t punish: “Punishing slackers Part 2”

ByEd Yong
March 19, 2008
9 min read

Two weeks ago, I wrote about a Science paper which looked at the effects of punishment in different societies across the world. Through a series of fascinating psychological experiments, the paper showed that the ability to punish freeloaders stabilises cooperative behaviour, bringing out the selfless side in people by making things more difficult for cheaters. The paper also showed that ‘antisocial punishment’, where the punished seek revenge on the punishers, derails the high levels of cooperation that other fairer forms of punishment help to entrench.

Punisher.jpg

Now a new study published in that other minor journal Nature adds another twist to the story. In it, Anna Dreber, Martin Nowak and colleagues from Harvard University confirm that groups of people are indeed more likely to cooperate if they can dole out punishment, but they also reap smaller rewards. In Dreber’s experiments, the groups that left with the highest payoffs were those that shunned punishment completely. It’s a conclusion best summed up by the stark and simple title of their paper: “Winners don’t punish.” 

Dreber revealed the dark side of punishment by modifying one of the classic experiments of game theory – the Prisoner’s Dilemma. Inspired by the plight of separately interrogated prisoners, the game pits two players who have a choice to cooperate or defect. For each ‘prisoner’, the best choice no matter what his partner does is to defect, but if they both defect, their outcomes are far poorer than if they had both cooperated – hence the dilemma.

The artificial scenario represents many real-world choices where cooperation is good for a group but cheating is best for the individual. When defection presents such stark benefits, evolutionary theory predicts that it should be commonplace unless some force can maintain cooperation. Recently, costly punishment – where an individual can suffer slightly to punish a cheater – has been mooted as such as force, because people avoid cheating for fear of reprisals. 

A further dilemma

To test this idea, Dreber extended the Prisoner’s Dilemma so that on every turn, players could punish as well as cooperate or defect. She recruited 104 local college students to play anonymously against each other. They were given a set of virtual tokens, informed about their options in neutral language and asked to make their moves together. Once played, the results were tallied and the choices revealed. The games went on for different times but players knew that every round had a one in four chance of being the last one. At the end of each game, each player was paid a dime for every remaining point.

Punishmenttable.jpg

In one game (T1), cooperation meant paying 1 token for the other player to receive 2, defection meant taking 1 token from the other player and adding it to your pot, and punishment meant paying 1 unit to fine the other person 4.  The second game (T2) was exactly the same, except that cooperation was more valuable, with the beneficiaries receiving 3 tokens instead of 2. The table on the right shows what happens for different combinations of choices. Alongside T1 and T2, Dreber also ran two control experiments (C1 and C2) where players could only cooperate or defect. Punishment wasn’t an option.

Gameresults.jpg

As the experiments unfolded, a number of different strategies became apparent. Some games were all-out cooperation (a). In others, one player defected but cooperation was restored when the other player either turned the other cheek (d) or defected in retaliation (c). In the face of forgiveness or the threat of mutual loss, the original defector decided to play fair again.

LIMITED TIME OFFER

Get a FREE tote featuring 1 of 7 ICONIC PLACES OF THE WORLD

When punishment was played, it usually didn’t restore cooperation. In some cases, the rebuked player simply carried on defecting only to be punished even further (b). When a punished player retaliated in kind (the ‘antisocial punishment’ studied in the earlier post), the game ended in mutually assured destruction (e). Finally, the ability to punish allowed irrational individuals to inflict harm on the undeserving with unprovoked pre-emptive strikes that had disastrous results for cooperation (g).

Payoffs

Even though actually taking punitive measures proved to be an anathema to teamwork, the option to punish did increase the overall levels of cooperation. In the two games that allowed punishment, T1 and T2, players chose to cooperate in 52% and 60% of their moves, but they only did so in 21% and 43% of the moves in the punishment-free control games, C1 and C2.

That seems like a good case for punishment, but not so. Dreber found no difference between the average takings in the two setups that included punishment (T1 and T2) and the two that didn’t (C1 and C2). As far as the groups were concerned, the ability to punish bore no benefits. At an individual level, things were even worse, for the players who came away with the least money were also those who meted out punishment most frequently. In the T1 game, for example, the five players who ended up richest were those who never punished their opponents (see graphs below; g = T1; h= T2).

Punishmentrank.jpg

You might suspect that these winners were just lucky and only faced opponents who always cooperated and never deserved punishment. But that wasn’t the case – their opponents occasionally defected too and the one strategic choice that set the winners apart from the losers was how they dealt with a defection.  Simply put, losers chose to punish while  winners opted for a ‘tit-for-tat’ strategy and defected themselves. Winners, it seems, really don’t punish.

The origins of punishment

The Science paper by Hermann et al actually found similar patterns In it, players from 16 cities showed more cooperative behaviour when they were allowed to punish their colleagues than when they weren’t. But the supplemental data reveal that 13 of these groups actually ended up with lower average earnings in the games that involved punishment than those that did not. Only 3 groups netted higher payoffs and Dreber suspects that the differences were not statistically significant. She said, “I believe that our results agree with those of Hermann et al.: punishment leads to more cooperation, but not higher payoffs.”

The results are a blow for the notion that costly punishment was critical for the evolution of human cooperation, for people who resort to punishment suffer for it. Instead, the authors suggest that costly punishment may have evolved for other reasons, like establishing pecking orders or allowing stronger members of a group to dominate weaker ones through coercion.

This is the second time I’ve written about a paper from Martin Nowak’s research group and both papers had two things in remarkably clear and witty language. Though the new study is published in a journal that can often be incomprehensible even to hardcore scientists, it is replete with, economical turns of phrase and lay language – anyone could pick it up and get the point.

Such a feat is both rare and applaudable. To be fair, the subject matter lends itself somewhat to more pithy writing but I have seen other papers in a similar field that still managed to be far more unintelligible than this one. Dreber, Nowak and her co-authors should be commended for their efforts. Their own conclusion to the paper sums up the research better than I ever could:

“People engage in conflicts and know that conflicts can carry costs. Costly punishment serves to escalate conflicts, not to moderate them. [It] might force people to submit, but not to cooperate… Winners do not use costly punishment, whereas losers punish and perish.”

Reference:Dreber, A., Rand, D.G., Fudenberg, D., Nowak, M.A. (2008). Winners don’t punish. Nature, 452(7185), 348-351. DOI: 10.1038/nature06723

Go Further